Gallagher sobre G-20: Quem paga a conta dos pacote anti-crise dos EUA? Os países em desenvolvimento, especialmente o Brasil.

The Real News Network: Who Pays the Bill for the Fed’s QE2?

Kevin Gallagher: Quantitative easing forces crippling cost on developing countries

PAUL JAY, SENIOR EDITOR, TRNN: Welcome to The Real News Network. I’m Paul Jay, coming to you today from Tufts University in Boston. On 11 and 12 November, the G-20 countries will be meeting in South Korea, supposedly to stop a currency war. And Ben Bernanke made his contribution to either stopping, or some people thinking starting a currency war. As you must’ve heard by now, QE2—not the boat, and not the Titanic, though maybe it will come to be known as that. At any rate, Quantitative Easing 2: put more money into the system, supposedly to be a stimulus. Well, what effect will this have in terms of the currency war and on other countries? Now joining us to discuss all of this is Kevin Gallagher. He’s an associate professor of international relations at Boston University and senior researcher at the Global Development and Environment Institute, Tufts University. Thanks for joining us.

KEVIN GALLAGHER, ASSOC. PROF. INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS, BOSTON UNIVERSITY: Thanks for having me, Paul.

JAY: So you recently wrote a piece in the The Guardian. The title is “Who pays the bill for the Fed’s QE2? By depressing US interest rates, quantitative easing forces developing countries to defend their currencies at crippling cost”. So what do you mean by that?

GALLAGHER: One of the unintended effects of QE2 is that there are going to be massive capital flows from The United States to emerging markets or developing countries. Why? Because with the interest rate low, banks and investors can borrow money in the United States and then park it places where there’s going to be a higher interest rate. This is called the carry trade, what nerds like me refer to it as. So you’re pulling money out of the United States at a low interest rate, 2, 3, 4 percent, parking it somewhere like Brazil, 10.53 percent. That’s an amazing, quick markup. Can’t get that in the US economy anywhere.

JAY: This essentially is the Fed is loaning money to the big banks at practically zero, or big corporations can also get hold of money very cheaply and play this spread as well.

GALLAGHER: Yeah, anyone who wants to be involved in global investing, in the carry trade. It’s one of the options that big-money investors look at when they’re looking around for different options to invest in, and this is a fairly lucrative one. It’s been very accentuated since 2008 because interest rates are already relatively low, but interest rates are relatively higher in developing countries, so there’s been massive inflows of capital to the developing world. It has two effects. One, it raises their currencies, so their exports are more expensive. Brazil’s currency’s increased by 37 percent since 2008. Their stuff’s more expensive out there in the world. So as we are trying to stimulate our economy, they can’t get many markets around the world because their stuff’s too expensive. That’s one thing. The other thing that’s perhaps even more concerning is the fact that this is speculative capital that’s going to move in and out of their country and could cause asset bubbles in other parts of their economy. And just as quick as it comes in, if there’s a change the interest rate in the United States or a little scare in a country, it can pull right out and destabilize their financial system.

JAY: So just to get it clear again, the Fed buys Treasury bills, T-bills, from big banks, or loans money very cheaply to corporate clients, but that goes through the big banks. You get—the cash goes to zero to the big banks, who make some of their own investments overseas. Or if you’re a AAA corporate lender, you borrow at 2, 3 percent from the big banks, and now you take the cash to these emerging markets and it has the consequences you were talking about. So, first of all, how is this any stimulus for the American economy, which is supposedly the objective of this whole plan?

GALLAGHER: Well, we have to realize we’re in a world of financial globalization now. So if you’ve got an open financial system, investors can take money from one country and put in another country if they see that they can get returns. So it’s perfectly legal. It’s unintended. And one of the—.

JAY: Or is it unintended? Is the objective of this plan to force inflation in these other countries, raise the prices of their goods, and that way make American products more purchasable here and more exportable? I mean, is this in fact just about a currency war?

GALLAGHER: I’m not sure it’s just about a currency war, but it’s clearly going to be an effect, and developing countries around the world are already lining up at the Fed with placards, saying, you shouldn’t have done this and you’re going to pay for it at the G-20 later on this week.

JAY: What does Bernanke say in response to the critique?

GALLAGHER: Bernanke said that the US is trying to get its own ship in order, and you should try to get your own ship in order. What they’re going to do to get their own ship in order is put in place capital controls. These are instruments to try to keep these short-term hot money out of their country. They’ll also accumulate more T-bills or accumulate more reserves to be able to make sure that their currencies are more stable.

JAY: Now, I was reading in your article that the recommendation to Colombia—I’m not sure if it came from the World Bank or not—actually saying they should have controls over this influx of capital, but Colombia doesn’t want to.

GALLAGHER: Yeah, there’s been a sea change in thinking about capital controls over the past 18 to 20 months. John Maynard Keynes, when he originally put together the international financial architecture, used to say that capital controls were a core part of the global financial system. Well, with neoliberal reforms and the rise of the IMF and the World Bank in the 1980s, these things became an evil specter. But, interestingly, they’ve come back, and they’ve come back in full force. There’s been a number of studies by people like myself, by the IMF, by the Asian Development Bank, saying that capital controls have worked, and as a matter of fact, those countries that use capital controls were among the least worse off with this current crisis. So, yes, in Colombia, the IMF was there last week and said, one of the things you might want to consider, because you’re getting so much capital into your country, is using capital controls. And Colombia said, I thought we weren’t allowed to use those things. And they said, yes, they’re now sanctioned. And Colombia said, well, if there’s not a stigma, we’ll reconsider.

JAY: Give us some specific examples how this is what you say a “crippling cost” for some of the emerging economies. Give us an example of what that is.

GALLAGHER: Well, there’s two things, right? One of the things is reserve accumulation. That’s where the biggest cost is. So if I need to stabilize my currency, if there’s all this hot money coming to my country, dollars coming into my country, alright, that is going to raise the level of my currency. And so what I need to do is buy those dollars, get them off the street. And I do that by taking my own currency and purchasing those dollars so there’s a lot of my currency out on the street. The more of it [there] is, the cheaper that it is, it’ll keep down the currency. Well, those dollars, by purpose, have a low interest rate, and so the returns for that investment that a country’s going to make are relatively low. And emerging markets, developing countries are growing faster than the US, so they can be putting the money into their own country. And there’s been a number of studies that have shown that the economic costs are significant. A Harvard economist did a study that showed that the economic costs of purchasing reserves is about 1 percent of your GDP. So it’s a 1 percent GDP loss for many countries.

JAY: These US dollars are coming in. They’re flooding into my market. Let’s say I’m an emerging economy. So they’re doing what? They are lending it to people, they are buying assets, they’re buying real estate. What are they doing with this money?

GALLAGHER: Well, they can park it in a bank, because it’s going to have a higher interest rate. They can move bonds from one country to another. It really depends.

JAY: So right now, if you went to a bank, for example in Brazil, you’re saying you can get 9 to 10 percent?

GALLAGHER: It’s over 10—10.57.

JAY: It’s over 10, by just putting it into a bank

GALLAGHER: Just by putting it into a bank.

JAY: So now that money’s in the bank, a Brazilian bank. It’s sitting on the money. It’s paying 9, 10 percent. It’s loaning it out at—.

GALLAGHER: Honestly, I can’t tell you exactly what the rate is that they’re doing.

JAY: But it’s got to be more than that. But there’s also got to be a market for it.

GALLAGHER: Sure, there’s a real market [inaudible]

JAY: Or they wouldn’t be paying 10. So the economies are getting so hot, people are willing to pay that kind of money.

GALLAGHER: Exactly. And one of the—these economies are growing so fast. Brazil’s going to grow at over 6 percent this year. The emerging markets are growing 6, 7 percent. And so there’s all sorts of folks that will buy these things at a higher premium.

JAY: Okay. Just explain the mechanism, why that inflates the value of the Brazilian currency. Now, the dollars hit the Brazilian banks. How does that get to that? How does that equal—?

GALLAGHER: Alright. So the influx of massive capital into developing countries, say in Brazil, raises the value of the currency because there’s more demand for the currency.

JAY: Because for these dollars to do anything in Brazil, they have to be transferred into Brazilian currency.

GALLAGHER: They have to purchase reals.

JAY: So they’re buying Brazilian, which ups the rate ‘cause there’s now a big demand for Brazilian currency, which also affects the cost of their exports.

GALLAGHER: Absolutely.

JAY: Okay. So explain how buying reserves opposes that if you’re the Brazilian government.

GALLAGHER: Sure. So if you’ve got an influx of money coming into your economy, there’s all these dollars in your economy, right? So you need to get those off the street. And so what you do is use your own currency, you purchase dollars, and there’s more of your own currency on the road. And therefore, if there’s more of it, it’s less scarce and it’s going to stabilize your currency, right?

JAY: And you deflate your currency.

GALLAGHER: You deflate your own currency.

JAY: So, in other words, it’s a countermeasure. So if one of the objectives of QE2 was to raise the value of other currencies in order to induce people to buy more American products, this counteracts that. So you wind up in a currency war where these economies just wind up at the same net result, except the banks make a ton of money on the way.

GALLAGHER: Sure. The Brazilian finance minister has already said we’re in the middle of a currency war and that the QE2 is only going to accentuate this. What’s ironic is we’re going into the G-20, and this is supposed to be the conversation where the US was the country that said, there are a number of things that other countries want to deal with at the G-20 meeting to get out of this crisis, but we really want to focus on currencies, because the US is concerned about China. Then we make this move a week before the meeting where we’re the ones who devalue our currency. It doesn’t put us on great standing going into these meetings.

JAY: Now, the Chinese are pegged to the US dollar, Chinese currency. So does it actually affect them, this QE2?

GALLAGHER: No. They’re pegged, so they purchase more dollars as our currency deflates, which increases the value of their reserves, and their reserves are almost $3 trillion already. The accumulation of all these reserves is one of the core reasons why we have this financial crisis, right, that these Asian countries, for the most part China, have been accumulating so many reserves. This has accentuated what we’re calling the global imbalances. So in order to save your country or your currency from this effort, we actually have to—many developing countries are accentuating some of the root causes of the crisis. 

PAUL JAY, SENIOR EDITOR, TRNN: Welcome to The Real News Network. I’m Paul Jay, coming to you today from Tufts University in Boston. On 11 and 12 November, the G-20 countries will be meeting in South Korea, supposedly to stop a currency war. And Ben Bernanke made his contribution to either stopping, or some people thinking starting a currency war. As you must’ve heard by now, QE2—not the boat, and not the Titanic, though maybe it will come to be known as that. At any rate, Quantitative Easing 2: put more money into the system, supposedly to be a stimulus. Well, what effect will this have in terms of the currency war and on other countries? Now joining us to discuss all of this is Kevin Gallagher. He’s an associate professor of international relations at Boston University and senior researcher at the Global Development and Environment Institute, Tufts University. Thanks for joining us.

KEVIN GALLAGHER, ASSOC. PROF. INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS, BOSTON UNIVERSITY: Thanks for having me, Paul.

JAY: So you recently wrote a piece in the The Guardian. The title is “Who pays the bill for the Fed’s QE2? By depressing US interest rates, quantitative easing forces developing countries to defend their currencies at crippling cost”. So what do you mean by that?

GALLAGHER: One of the unintended effects of QE2 is that there are going to be massive capital flows from The United States to emerging markets or developing countries. Why? Because with the interest rate low, banks and investors can borrow money in the United States and then park it places where there’s going to be a higher interest rate. This is called the carry trade, what nerds like me refer to it as. So you’re pulling money out of the United States at a low interest rate, 2, 3, 4 percent, parking it somewhere like Brazil, 10.53 percent. That’s an amazing, quick markup. Can’t get that in the US economy anywhere.

JAY: This essentially is the Fed is loaning money to the big banks at practically zero, or big corporations can also get hold of money very cheaply and play this spread as well.

GALLAGHER: Yeah, anyone who wants to be involved in global investing, in the carry trade. It’s one of the options that big-money investors look at when they’re looking around for different options to invest in, and this is a fairly lucrative one. It’s been very accentuated since 2008 because interest rates are already relatively low, but interest rates are relatively higher in developing countries, so there’s been massive inflows of capital to the developing world. It has two effects. One, it raises their currencies, so their exports are more expensive. Brazil’s currency’s increased by 37 percent since 2008. Their stuff’s more expensive out there in the world. So as we are trying to stimulate our economy, they can’t get many markets around the world because their stuff’s too expensive. That’s one thing. The other thing that’s perhaps even more concerning is the fact that this is speculative capital that’s going to move in and out of their country and could cause asset bubbles in other parts of their economy. And just as quick as it comes in, if there’s a change the interest rate in the United States or a little scare in a country, it can pull right out and destabilize their financial system.

JAY: So just to get it clear again, the Fed buys Treasury bills, T-bills, from big banks, or loans money very cheaply to corporate clients, but that goes through the big banks. You get—the cash goes to zero to the big banks, who make some of their own investments overseas. Or if you’re a AAA corporate lender, you borrow at 2, 3 percent from the big banks, and now you take the cash to these emerging markets and it has the consequences you were talking about. So, first of all, how is this any stimulus for the American economy, which is supposedly the objective of this whole plan?

GALLAGHER: Well, we have to realize we’re in a world of financial globalization now. So if you’ve got an open financial system, investors can take money from one country and put in another country if they see that they can get returns. So it’s perfectly legal. It’s unintended. And one of the—.

JAY: Or is it unintended? Is the objective of this plan to force inflation in these other countries, raise the prices of their goods, and that way make American products more purchasable here and more exportable? I mean, is this in fact just about a currency war?

GALLAGHER: I’m not sure it’s just about a currency war, but it’s clearly going to be an effect, and developing countries around the world are already lining up at the Fed with placards, saying, you shouldn’t have done this and you’re going to pay for it at the G-20 later on this week.

JAY: What does Bernanke say in response to the critique?

GALLAGHER: Bernanke said that the US is trying to get its own ship in order, and you should try to get your own ship in order. What they’re going to do to get their own ship in order is put in place capital controls. These are instruments to try to keep these short-term hot money out of their country. They’ll also accumulate more T-bills or accumulate more reserves to be able to make sure that their currencies are more stable.

JAY: Now, I was reading in your article that the recommendation to Colombia—I’m not sure if it came from the World Bank or not—actually saying they should have controls over this influx of capital, but Colombia doesn’t want to.

GALLAGHER: Yeah, there’s been a sea change in thinking about capital controls over the past 18 to 20 months. John Maynard Keynes, when he originally put together the international financial architecture, used to say that capital controls were a core part of the global financial system. Well, with neoliberal reforms and the rise of the IMF and the World Bank in the 1980s, these things became an evil specter. But, interestingly, they’ve come back, and they’ve come back in full force. There’s been a number of studies by people like myself, by the IMF, by the Asian Development Bank, saying that capital controls have worked, and as a matter of fact, those countries that use capital controls were among the least worse off with this current crisis. So, yes, in Colombia, the IMF was there last week and said, one of the things you might want to consider, because you’re getting so much capital into your country, is using capital controls. And Colombia said, I thought we weren’t allowed to use those things. And they said, yes, they’re now sanctioned. And Colombia said, well, if there’s not a stigma, we’ll reconsider.

JAY: Give us some specific examples how this is what you say a “crippling cost” for some of the emerging economies. Give us an example of what that is.

GALLAGHER: Well, there’s two things, right? One of the things is reserve accumulation. That’s where the biggest cost is. So if I need to stabilize my currency, if there’s all this hot money coming to my country, dollars coming into my country, alright, that is going to raise the level of my currency. And so what I need to do is buy those dollars, get them off the street. And I do that by taking my own currency and purchasing those dollars so there’s a lot of my currency out on the street. The more of it [there] is, the cheaper that it is, it’ll keep down the currency. Well, those dollars, by purpose, have a low interest rate, and so the returns for that investment that a country’s going to make are relatively low. And emerging markets, developing countries are growing faster than the US, so they can be putting the money into their own country. And there’s been a number of studies that have shown that the economic costs are significant. A Harvard economist did a study that showed that the economic costs of purchasing reserves is about 1 percent of your GDP. So it’s a 1 percent GDP loss for many countries.

JAY: These US dollars are coming in. They’re flooding into my market. Let’s say I’m an emerging economy. So they’re doing what? They are lending it to people, they are buying assets, they’re buying real estate. What are they doing with this money?

GALLAGHER: Well, they can park it in a bank, because it’s going to have a higher interest rate. They can move bonds from one country to another. It really depends.

JAY: So right now, if you went to a bank, for example in Brazil, you’re saying you can get 9 to 10 percent?

GALLAGHER: It’s over 10—10.57.

JAY: It’s over 10, by just putting it into a bank

GALLAGHER: Just by putting it into a bank.

JAY: So now that money’s in the bank, a Brazilian bank. It’s sitting on the money. It’s paying 9, 10 percent. It’s loaning it out at—.

GALLAGHER: Honestly, I can’t tell you exactly what the rate is that they’re doing.

JAY: But it’s got to be more than that. But there’s also got to be a market for it.

GALLAGHER: Sure, there’s a real market [inaudible]

JAY: Or they wouldn’t be paying 10. So the economies are getting so hot, people are willing to pay that kind of money.

GALLAGHER: Exactly. And one of the—these economies are growing so fast. Brazil’s going to grow at over 6 percent this year. The emerging markets are growing 6, 7 percent. And so there’s all sorts of folks that will buy these things at a higher premium.

JAY: Okay. Just explain the mechanism, why that inflates the value of the Brazilian currency. Now, the dollars hit the Brazilian banks. How does that get to that? How does that equal—?

GALLAGHER: Alright. So the influx of massive capital into developing countries, say in Brazil, raises the value of the currency because there’s more demand for the currency.

JAY: Because for these dollars to do anything in Brazil, they have to be transferred into Brazilian currency.

GALLAGHER: They have to purchase reals.

JAY: So they’re buying Brazilian, which ups the rate ‘cause there’s now a big demand for Brazilian currency, which also affects the cost of their exports.

GALLAGHER: Absolutely.

JAY: Okay. So explain how buying reserves opposes that if you’re the Brazilian government.

GALLAGHER: Sure. So if you’ve got an influx of money coming into your economy, there’s all these dollars in your economy, right? So you need to get those off the street. And so what you do is use your own currency, you purchase dollars, and there’s more of your own currency on the road. And therefore, if there’s more of it, it’s less scarce and it’s going to stabilize your currency, right?

JAY: And you deflate your currency.

GALLAGHER: You deflate your own currency.

JAY: So, in other words, it’s a countermeasure. So if one of the objectives of QE2 was to raise the value of other currencies in order to induce people to buy more American products, this counteracts that. So you wind up in a currency war where these economies just wind up at the same net result, except the banks make a ton of money on the way.

GALLAGHER: Sure. The Brazilian finance minister has already said we’re in the middle of a currency war and that the QE2 is only going to accentuate this. What’s ironic is we’re going into the G-20, and this is supposed to be the conversation where the US was the country that said, there are a number of things that other countries want to deal with at the G-20 meeting to get out of this crisis, but we really want to focus on currencies, because the US is concerned about China. Then we make this move a week before the meeting where we’re the ones who devalue our currency. It doesn’t put us on great standing going into these meetings.

JAY: Now, the Chinese are pegged to the US dollar, Chinese currency. So does it actually affect them, this QE2?

GALLAGHER: No. They’re pegged, so they purchase more dollars as our currency deflates, which increases the value of their reserves, and their reserves are almost $3 trillion already. The accumulation of all these reserves is one of the core reasons why we have this financial crisis, right, that these Asian countries, for the most part China, have been accumulating so many reserves. This has accentuated what we’re calling the global imbalances. So in order to save your country or your currency from this effort, we actually have to—many developing countries are accentuating some of the root causes of the crisis.

Fonte: http://therealnews.com/t2/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=31&Itemid=74&jumival=5855

vejam outras matérias sobre a crise econômica mundial

Postado por

Luiz Albuquerque

Comissão do Senado aprova proposta que aumenta intervenção federal em Estados

A CCJ (Comissão de Constituição e Justiça) do Senado aprovou uma proposta que aumenta a possibilidade de intervenção federal em Estados onde houver indícios de irregularidades praticadas pelo governador ou integrantes do Poder Legislativo local. A PEC (Proposta de Emenda Constitucional) afirma que, quando houver “fundados indícios” de que a maioria absoluta da Assembleia Legislativa está sujeita à perda de mandato, a intervenção deve ser decretada pelo presidente da República.

A proposta também inclui como hipótese para intervenção o afastamento do governador envolvido em práticas incompatíveis com o exercício do cargo. Pela proposta, caberá ao Senado julgar o governador afastado –caso o Poder Legislativo local esteja envolvido nas irregularidades.

Aos senadores, ainda caberá legislar no lugar da Assembleia Legislativa se ficar decretada a intervenção. “Estando sob suspeição a maioria dos seus integrantes, torna-se impossível a instalação de processo com um mínimo de legitimidade”, disse o senador Tião Viana (PT-AC), autor da PEC.

A Constituição Federal prevê, atualmente, a intervenção federal nos seguintes casos: manter a integridade nacional; repelir invasão estrangeira ou de uma unidade da federação em outra; pôr termo a grave comprometimento da ordem pública; garantir o livre exercício de qualquer dos Poderes nas unidades da federação e reorganizar as finanças da unidade da federação.

A proposta segue para análise do plenário do Senado. Se for aprovada, será enviada para votação na Câmara.

FISCALIZAÇÃO

A comissão também decidiu endurecer o controle sobre as agências reguladoras, que podem passar a ter seu desempenho avaliado pela Casa Legislativa. Proposta de emenda constitucional aprovada hoje pela CCJ determina que, além da fiscalização, o Senado e a Câmara poderão a convocar diretores das agências ou titulares de órgãos subordinados à Presidência da República para prestarem esclarecimentos ao Congresso – regra aplicada hoje somente aos ministros de Estado.

A PEC determina que, se a autoridade não atender à convocação, pode responder por crime de responsabilidade. Segundo o texto, o Congresso passa a ter autonomia para avaliar, pelo menos uma vez por ano, o desempenho das atividades da agência reguladora. “Com essas propostas, esperamos aperfeiçoar os mecanismos de fiscalização e autuação do parlamento brasileiro, sem aumentar o risco regulatório ou comprometer a estrutura jurídico-constitucional do Estado brasileiro”, disse o autor da PEC, senador Aloizio Mercadante (PT-SP).

A proposta seguiu para votação em plenário e, se aprovada, será enviada à Câmara para análise.

Fonte: Folha

Autor: Huarlei Oliveira

Entenda a chamada ‘guerra cambial’

Na próxima semana, líderes das principais economias do mundo estarão reunidos em Seul, na Coreia do Sul, para debater o futuro da economia mundial. Dois anos após o ápice da crise financeira, no entanto, o centro das discussões promete ser a chamada “guerra cambial”.

Como consequencia da reação dos Estados Unidos à crise, o dólar vem perdendo valor frente a uma série de moedas. Essa desvalorização prejudica as exportações dos demais países, que vêem seus produtos se tornarem mais caros no mercado externo. A reação vem na forma de medidas unilaterais.

Na quarta-feira, o Comitê de Políica Monetária do Fed (Federal Reserve, o BC dos EUA) anunciou que irá adquirir mais US$ 600 bilhões em títulos públicos até a metade do próximo ano, como forma de injetar resursos na economia local.

As economias emergentes avaliaram que a medida – que foi alvo de críticas em todo o mundo – torna improvável um acordo significativo para reduzir os desequilíbrios globais na reunião do G20.

“Todo mundo quer que a economia americana se recupere, porém não adianta ficar jogando dólar de helicóptero”, disse o ministro da fazenda, Guido Mantega, em Brasília, nesta quinta. Segundo o ministro, é improvável que tal medida estimule o crescimento da economia global, podendo, por outro lado, agravar os desequilíbrios mundiais, preocupação também compratilhada pela China.

“Enquanto o mundo não exercer restrição à emissão de moedas de reserva como o dólar – e isso não é fácil -, a ocorrência de outra crise é inevitável, escreveu Xia Bin, assessor do Banco Central da China, em um jornal administrado pela autoridade monetária.

Reclamações sobre a política monetária dos EUA também patiram do mundo desenvolvido. O ministro da economia alemã, Rainer Bruederle, afirmou estar preocupado com que os Estados Unidos estejam tentando estimular o crescimento ao injetar liquidez na economia. Sua colega francesa, Christine Lagarde, disse que a reação das economias emergentes mostra a necessidade de reformas.

O presidente do Branco Central Europeu (BCE), Jean-Claude Trichet, disse estar confiante de que os Estados Unidos ainda apoiam um dólar forte.

O secratário geral da Conferência da ONU para o Comércio e Desenvolvimento, Supachai Panitchpakdi, alertou que o resultado desse tipo de medida tem sido a transferência dos rescursos para mercados emergentes em forma de capital especulativo. “Mais uma vez, o problema nos países ricos está sendo exportado.”

Fonte: globo.com/economia

Postado por Marina Rodrigues

(Des)União Europeia

Itália enfrenta uma crise política entre Berlusconi e Fini. Alemanha acomoda o lixo nuclear francês e expande seu projeto para desativar 17 centrais nucleares. França é acusada de colocar interesses econômicos à frente dos direitos humanos.

A Europa vêm passando por um momento de questionáveis decisões, principalmente políticas e sociais. A União Europeia, a partir de dezembro, passará a exigir dos cidadãos da Albânia e da Bósnia visto para entrar no território dos Vinte e Sete.

Mas Bruxelas deixa um aviso. Em caso de abusos, o sistema de vistos volta a ser reposto aos dois países. União Europeia: deciões necessárias ou para fechar o cerco?

A “cláusula de revisão” imposta à Bósnia e à Albânia é inédita. A União Europeia (UE) não quer viver o mesmo que há cerca de um ano. Em Dezembro de 2009 aboliu os vistos para a Macedónia, Montenegro e Sérvia e viu explodir o fluxo de imigrantes e pedidos de asilo. Está evidente que nem todos os países membros concordam com a decisão.

Por

Leo Fávaro

Mas Bruxelas deixa um aviso. Em caso de abusos, o sistema de vistos volta a ser reposto aos dois países.

Mesmo assim, uma habitante de Sarajevo diz: “Estou contente com a supressão dos vistos. Preciso de ir à Alemanha, conheci um alemão e decidimos casar lá”. Outro acrescenta: “O que aconteceu é bom, mas a nossa situação financeira continua na mesma. Aqueles que têm dinheiro vão continuar a viajar e quem não tem fica em casa”.

A “cláusula de revisão” imposta à Bósnia e à Albânia é inédita. A União Europeia (UE) não quer viver o mesmo que há cerca de um ano. Em Dezembro de 2009 aboliu os vistos para a Macedónia, Montenegro e Sérvia e viu explodir o fluxo de imigrantes e pedidos de asilo.

Blowback: Como o intervensionismo dos EUA gerou ódio no mundo inteiro

“Por que ele nos odeiam?”

Pergunta comum após o 11/09/2001

Chalmers Johnson, author of Blowback, Sorrows of Empire and Nemesis: The Last Days of the American Republic , talks about the U.S. ‘military-petroleum complex,’ the overextension of the American military, nuclear proliferation, and the decline of Washington’s credibility abroad.

Chalmers Johnson is president of the Japan Policy Research Institute, a non-profit research and public affairs organization devoted to public education concerning Japan and international relations in the Pacific. http://www.jpri.org/

Postado por

Luiz Albuquerque

“Cuba não liberta presos e ativistas ameaçam com onda de protestos” pela BBC

As Damas de Branco fazem passeta em Havana 

As ‘Damas de Branco’ prometeram lançar uma onda de ações pela libertação dos dissidentes

Ativistas da oposição em Cuba acusaram o governo de não ter cumprido a promessa de libertar 13 dissidentes políticos até domingo.

O presidente Raúl Castro tinha anunciado em julho que libertaria 52 prisioneiros políticos nos quatro meses seguintes.

Trinta e nove destes foram libertados e se encontram no exílio na Espanha, mas 13 continuam encarcerados porque se recusam a deixar o país.

As “Damas de Branco”, grupo formado por esposas e mães de prisioneiros políticos cubanos, disseram que, segundo os termos de um acordo entre Castro e a Igreja Católica do país, o prazo da libertação expirava no domingo.

O grupo fez uma manifestação em Havana e prometeu lançar uma onda de ações como greves de fome e passeatas até que os dissidentes sejam libertados.

“Eles estão enganando a igreja, o governo da Espanha, a União Europeia e toda a comunidade internacional”, disse a líder das Damas de Branco, Laura Pollan.

Um representante da igreja disse estar surpreso com a falta de progresso em relação à situação dos prisioneiros.

“Não é o que a gente pensava que fosse ocorrer”, disse José Felix Perez, secretário da Conferência Cubana de Bispos, à agência de notícias Associated Press.

O conhecido dissidente cubano Guillermo Farinas indicou que está pronto para iniciar uma nova greve de fome caso os 13 prisioneiros não sejam libertados.

Farinas, que no mês passado ganhou o prêmio Sakharov de direitos humanos, concedido pelo Parlamento Europeu, encerrou no início de julho uma greve de fome de mais de quatro meses, depois do anúncio da libertação dos 52 presos políticos.

Apesar de ter feito um acordo com a Igreja Católica e o governo da Espanha prometendo libertar os prisioneiros, o governo cubano nunca se pronunciou oficialmente sobre um prazo para a libertação. Para o governo, os dissidentes presos são “mercenários” a serviço dos Estados Unidos.

Todos os 52 presos faziam parte do grupo de 75 dissidentes preso em 2003 e condenado a sentenças de entre seis e 28 anos de detenção.

Postado por Yasmin Riegert.

“Ritmo de expansão da economia brasileira diminui, diz OCDE” por Mário Camera da BBC

Imagem de arquivo de colheita no Mato Grosso
Redução no ritmo de crescimento já fora observado em meses anteriores

 

O ritmo de crescimento da economia brasileira está em desaceleração, segundo dados da OCDE (Organização para a Cooperação e Desenvolvimento Econômico) divulgados nesta segunda-feira em Paris.

A medição de setembro do Indicador Composto Avançado (ICA ou CLI, na sigla em inglês), calculado pela OCDE, mostra recuos consecutivos desde maio no ritmo em que a economia brasileira avança.

A OCDE aponta, em contrapartida, que a expansão ganha força em países que se recuperam de recessões, como Estados Unidos e Japão.

A redução de ritmo é “moderada” em Grã-Bretanha, Canadá, França, Índia e Itália e “fortemente” acentuada em Brasil e China. A tendência já havia sido observada no mês passado.

Clique Leia mais na BBC Brasil: Expansão econômica do Brasil pode estar perdendo fôlego, diz OCDE

O ICA se baseia em séries históricas de crescimento da produção industrial de cada país para calcular, mensalmente, as tendências econômicas dos 33 países da OCDE e de outros seis emergentes que não pertencem ao organismo. Não é uma medição de PIB, mas de tendência de crescimento.

O nível de 100 pontos é utilizado como referência para classificar a intensidade da atividade econômica dos países.

Os países que sofreram queda em relação ao último estudo e ficaram abaixo de 100 pontos recebem a classificação de “desaceleração”. Os que também tiveram diminuição do índice, mas permaneceram acima da barreira de 100 pontos, são considerados como em “leve desaceleração”.

Brasil e China são os únicos países avaliados a ficar abaixo dos 100 pontos (com 98,6 e 99,3, respectivamente) no relatório divulgado nesta segunda pela OCDE.

Ainda assim, o saldo brasileiro no ICA é positivo em 0,8 ponto percentual nos últimos 12 meses.

‘Divergências de crescimento’

A desaceleração não é a tendência predominante entre as economias, segundo o relatório da OCDE. O organismo destaca que o ICA para o mês de setembro mostra “divergências no ritmo de crescimento econômico dos países analisados”.

Com isso, a boa notícia vai para Alemanha, Japão, Estados Unidos e Rússia. Os ciclos de crescimento das economias dos quatro países “continuam em expansão”, informa o relatório da OCDE.

A economia alemã mostra que se recupera de maneira sólida da crise mundial, mantendo o ritmo de crescimento estável em setembro. Nos últimos doze meses, a Alemanha acumula a maior alta entre as economias analisadas, ao alcançar 105,8 pontos.

Com 102,4 pontos, os Estados Unidos têm uma “expansão estável”.

A Rússia é o único emergente a figurar entre os que devem manter um ritmo de crescimento sólido.

Entre os países que apresentam uma “leve desaceleração” do ritmo de crescimento de suas economias, a OCDE cita Grã-Bretanha e França. Mas o ritmo de expansão de ambos se mantém acima da barreira dos 100 pontos.

Postado por Yasmin Riegert.